One of many merits of James Jaffe's Striking a Bargain is that it reminds us that we know less about history of work than we think we do. In this important study, Jaffe takes aim at Webb-inspired orthodoxy that collective bargaining did not exist before 1860s. The first half of nineteenth century is still often held to be a period when primitive trade unions, labouring under legal restrictions, had to learn the rules of (in Eric Hobsbawm's phrase). At a more profound level, Jaffe is unhappy with market-based models of industrial relations in early industrial period. In a manner that reminds me of early work of William Reddy, Jaffe demonstrates how cultural as much as economic forces shaped trade union behaviour. Contrary to view that industrial relations were formless or devoid of institutions that would shape bargaining in later nineteenth century, Jaffe portrays a world of informal or semi-formal wage bargaining between industrial employers and employees that was frequently sophisticated and effective. In this twilight world, categories that mattered were not those of class or market so much as custom, honour, fairness, reciprocity, discretion, manliness, and an acknowledgement of interests. The key words for artisans in negotiations were fair play. Why has this form of bargaining been ignored? In part, evidence is scattered and anecdotal (problems dealt with by thoroughness of Jaffe's research). However, ifJaffe is correct, we suffer from a distorted view of labour process created by industrial novelists of 1840s and 1850s who did not bother to consider complexities of workplace. Not that economists do much better in Jaffe's account. Adam Smith certainly recognised wage bargaining but other contemporary economists failed to appreciate its importance in labour market.Jaffe, by contrast, explores work relations in a theoretically sophisticated way, importing ideas from game theory, intellectual history, political science, and postmodernism. Employers and workers, we discover, frequently bargained over wages before 1860. For example, price lists were employed to avoid dangers of competitive rate-cutting as part of a system of wage regulation that assisted both sides. Courts of Requests often dealt with disputes between management and labour, thus coming informally to regulate employment relations. Jaffe finds evidence of sophisticated bargaining amongst Macclesfield silk spinners, Coventry ribbon trade, Staffordshire potters, and northern coal miners (all of whom receive detailed case studies). For Jaffe, industrial relations in this period were not only highly ritualised but constituted a form of theatre. He is particularly interesting on dramaturgical structure of negotiations in which participants in effect played out different kinds of roles (a splendid example of author's interdisciplinary approach). Jaffe examines strikes and other breakdowns in employer/employee relations but does not see them as examples of class conflict. His theme is really that of social cooperation. Wage bargaining was a ritual in which people knew their lines in script. He considers ways in which power of employers was mediated by cultural considerations, leading to his reconsideration of labour relations (following Marcel Mauss) as a gift relationship. Such a view, which both sides bought into, did not mean, however, that workers saw themselves as subservient. What sustained labour relations was notion of reci-