Abstract

Reviewed by: Corporation Nation by Robert E. Wright William H. Becker Robert E. Wright, Corporation Nation. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2014. 328 pp. ISBN: 978-0-8122-4564-6, $69.95 (cloth). One outcome of the Great Recession has been a torrent of books on the origins and consequences of the financial collapse of 2008, as well as previous debacles in what might be called the era of Enron. Academics, journalists, and some defectors from the well-paid world of Wall Street have produced books that heighten our understanding of what has happened to the American corporate economy since the beginning of the twenty-first century. Perhaps, surprisingly, a book on the antebellum growth of incorporation should be added to the list of important works that contribute to our appreciation of the latest crisis. Robert E. Wright’s Corporation Nation provides a careful account of the legal structuring and governance of the first corporations. Knowledge of the safeguards embedded in the legal framework of the country’s initial corporate entities has been all but lost from the post-Civil War era through the twentieth century. Wright’s argument stems from a deep concern about the dangers inherent in the “agency principal problem” intrinsic to the corporate form. He maintains that the initially tightly governed antebellum corporations have evolved into very loosely governed corporations, which have contributed to the recent financial crises. If the stark weakening of corporate governance is not attended to, Wright fears an “existential” crisis as Americans broadly lose faith in stocks. [End Page 726] Incorporation in the antebellum economy created a tight governance system based, for the most part, on stockholders operating the enterprises in which they invested. State legislatures granted charters that spelled out the benefits that privileged the initial stockholders, such as “the ability to sue and be sued in their own name, perpetual succession, use of a corporate seal, limited liability, [and] share transferability”. In return, “early corporations were only supposed to engage in activities explicitly laid out in their charters, a concept tied to the legal doctrine called ‘ultra vires’” (p. 4). Wright’s analysis rests on a wide-ranging reading of economic and legal history and an impressive grasp of the writings about corporations by antebellum jurists, legislators, journalists, entrepreneurs, investors, merchants, and bankers. His work also illustrates the surprisingly broad scope of specially chartered businesses in the antebellum period. Wright and Richard Sylla found 22,419 such entities chartered between 1790 and 1860, based on data they assembled in a project sponsored by the National Science Foundation (NSF) (pp. 58–59). Wright’s findings challenge the work of a previous generation of historians who have for decades shaped our views of the corporation in the antebellum period. These scholars believed—and their views continue to appear in recent writings—that antebellum incorporations were confined to the infrastructure and banking sectors. Instead, Wright argues that a broad sweep of incorporated business entities stimulated economic growth by promoting local employment and economic activity, as the capital assembled through chartering helped corporations to realize scale economies, vertical integration, and a degree of market power. Tight governance in the antebellum period was not foolproof, of course. Managerial incompetence and fraud prompted ongoing debates about the role of state legislatures—and, later, Congress—in preventing corporate failure and abuse. The principal–agent problem increased concern because of “the intrinsic difficulty of managing large, complex organizations in a competitive environment” (p. 158). How best to limit fraud and ineptitude led to new state rules. To limit embezzlement, for example, large company checks had to be countersigned. More generally, banks and insurance companies were required to standardize accounting and actuarial rules. Fraud and mishandling of corporate affairs invited state legislative investigative committees to examine company affairs ever more closely. According to many corporate charters, such efforts should have been the responsibility of stockholders, not legislators. Banks were the most likely targets of legislative scrutiny, especially after the recession of 1819 and subsequent recessions. Some state legislatures rewrote charters to limit failures. They demanded increased capital reserves and [End Page 727] limited leverage to two or three times paid-in capital, exposing stockholders to greater liability and removal...

Full Text
Paper version not known

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call

Disclaimer: All third-party content on this website/platform is and will remain the property of their respective owners and is provided on "as is" basis without any warranties, express or implied. Use of third-party content does not indicate any affiliation, sponsorship with or endorsement by them. Any references to third-party content is to identify the corresponding services and shall be considered fair use under The CopyrightLaw.