Abstract

EUROPEAN GOVERNMENTS REDISTRIBUTE income among their citizens on a much larger scale than does the U.S. government. European social programs are more generous and reach a larger share of citizens. European tax systems are more progressive. European regulations designed to protect the poor are more intrusive. In this paper we try to understand why. The literature on the size of government is rich and varied. However, here we do not focus on the size of government as such, but rather on the redistributive side of government policies. Thus our goal is in one sense narrower than answering the question, What explains the size of government? since we focus on a single, but increasingly important, role of fiscal policy. Yet in another sense our focus is broader, because redistributive policies go beyond the government budget--think, for instance, of labor market policies. We consider economic, political, and behavioral explanations for these differences between the United States and Europe. Economic explanations focus on the variance of income and the skewness of the income distribution before taxes and transfers, the social costs of taxation, the volatility of income, and expected changes in income for the median voter. We conclude that most of these theories cannot explain the observed differences. Before-tax income in the United States has both a higher variance and a more skewed distribution. There is no evidence that the deadweight losses from taxation are lower in Europe. And the volatility of income appears to be lower in Europe than in the United States. However, there is some possibility that middle-class households in the United States have a greater chance of moving up in the income distribution, which would make the median voter more averse to redistribution. Political explanations for the observed level of redistribution focus on institutions that prevent minorities from gaining political power or that strictly protect individuals' private property. Cross-country comparisons indicate the importance of these institutions in limiting redistribution. For instance, at the federal level, the United States does not have proportional representation, which played an important role in facilitating the growth of socialist parties in many European countries. America has strong courts that have routinely rejected popular attempts at redistribution, such as the income tax or labor regulation. The European equivalents of these courts were swept away as democracy replaced monarchy and aristocracy. The federal structure of the United States may have also contributed to constraining the role of the central government in redistribution. These political institutions result from particular features of U.S. history and geography. The formation of the United States as a federation of independent territories led to a structure that often creates obstacles to centralized redistributive policies. The relative political stability of the United States over more than two centuries means that it is still governed by an eighteenth-century constitution designed to protect property. As world war and revolution uprooted the old European monarchies, the twentieth-century constitutions that replaced them were more oriented toward majority rule, and less toward protection of private property. Moreover, the spatial organization of the United States--in particular, its low population density--meant that the U.S. government was much less threatened by socialist revolution. In contrast, many of Europe's institutions were established either by revolutionary groups directly or by elites in response to the threat of violence. Finally, we discuss reciprocal altruism as a possible behavioral explanation for redistribution. Reciprocal altruism implies that voters will dislike giving money to the poor if, as in the United States, the poor are perceived as lazy. In contrast, Europeans overwhelmingly believe that the poor are poor because they have been unfortunate. …

Highlights

  • Rather we focus on the differences over space, not over time

  • The logic of this model is closely tied to the work of Benabou and Ok (2001), Perotti (2000), Picketty (1995), and many others, and this work should be seen as a synthesis, not as a new model

  • Theprevioussectionexploredreasonswhy politicalinstitutionscould explaindifferentlevels of redistributionin the UnitedStatesandEurope, even if the demandforredistributionwerethe samein bothplaces. we look at theories of why the demandfor redistributionmight differ betweenEuropeandthe UnitedStates,andin particularwhy the median voterin Europemightbe morepositivelydisposedtowardthe poorthan themedianvoterin theUnitedStates

Read more

Summary

Theory and Discussion

In this sectionwe presenta briefformalmodelon the determinantos f the level of redistribution.'W8 e model the welfare system as a schedule of transfersthatis indexedwitha singleparametert:hetaxrateon income t. The economic model presentedabovesuggeststhattherearetwo ways in which social mobility canexplainthegapbetweenU.S. andEuropeanlevelsof welfare.First, the medianvoterin the UnitedStatesmightexpecthigherfutureincome growth(relativeto otherAmericans)thandoesthemedianvoterinEurope According to this theory, high income mobility in the United States (upwardmobility of the medianvoter) can explain lower U.S redistribution.Second,Europeansmightdemandmoreredistribution becausetheyface moreexogenousshocksto theirincomes(perhaps because of the greateropennessof theireconomies), andredistribution reducesrisk.Accordingto thistheory,low incomemobilityin the United StatescouldexplainlowerU.S. redistribution. For this theory to explain differences in redistributionbetween the UnitedStatesandEurope,it mustbe thecase thatthemedianvoterin the UnitedStatesis morelikely thanthe medianEuropeanvoterto become richat some futuredate.Thisprobabilitycombineshighermobilitywith the specificchanceof movingupwardforindividualsin themiddleof the income distribution.Therearetwo types of evidence on this question: actualincomemobilitydataandsurveyquestionsaboutincomemobility. Forthis reason,MFPRconstruct(for a smallersampleof countries)a continuousvariablebased on the following idea They wantto capture the shareof electoralvotes thatguaranteesa partya parliamentarsyeatin anelectoraldistrictof averagesize.Thisvariable,labeledUMS(for"upper marginalshare"),is decliningin proportionalitys,incethehigheris UMS, the moredifficultit is for smallpartiesto gain access to parliamentI.

Findings
10 Australia
Conclusion
Full Text
Published version (Free)

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call