Abstract

People willingly accept personal costs to sanction norm violations even if they are not personally affected by the wrongdoing and even if their sanctioning yields no immediate benefits—a behavior known as third-party punishment. A notable body of literature suggests that this behavior is primarily driven by retribution (i.e., evening out the harm caused), rather than by the utilitarian motives of special prevention (i.e., preventing recidivism), or general prevention (i.e., preventing imitation). This has led to the conclusion that laypeople are “retributivists” in general. More recent evidence, however, raises doubts about the ubiquity of retributivism, showing that punishment is driven by multiple motives. The present research adds to this debate by investigating the motives underlying punishment in children around age 10. Specifically, we investigate children’s (N = 238) punishment motives in an economic game paradigm, isolating punishment motives by experimentally manipulating the extent to which the offender and a bystander learn about the punishment. This offers the possibility to examine whether (and to what extent) children engage in punishment even when it is devoid of any preventive effects. Results show that children’s punishment is motivated by retributive, special preventive, and general preventive purposes. These results point to a clear need for further theory specification on the motivational basis of punishment in humans and provide practical implications for the treatment of child misbehavior.

Highlights

  • People willingly sacrifice their own resources to sanction norm violations across a wide range of societies and contexts [1]

  • D2 reflects the contrast for special prevention, comparing the hidden punishment condition with the private punishment condition

  • The present research adds to the debate on the motivational basis of punishment by investigating punishment motives from a developmental perspective

Read more

Summary

Introduction

People willingly sacrifice their own resources (e.g., time or money) to sanction norm violations across a wide range of societies and contexts [1]. Many individuals accept some personal costs to punish offenders even if they are not affected by the wrongdoing, and even if their sanctioning does not yield any immediate benefits [2]. Behavioral economics, and related disciplines, this behavior is referred to as third-party punishment [3]. Researchers have sought to understand the underlying motives driving third-party punishment [4,5,6], focusing on two main motives: utilitarianism and retribution. According to a utilitarian approach, punishment is an instrument to decrease norm violations and increase people’s compliance with social norms [1, 3].

Objectives
Methods
Results
Conclusion
Full Text
Paper version not known

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call

Disclaimer: All third-party content on this website/platform is and will remain the property of their respective owners and is provided on "as is" basis without any warranties, express or implied. Use of third-party content does not indicate any affiliation, sponsorship with or endorsement by them. Any references to third-party content is to identify the corresponding services and shall be considered fair use under The CopyrightLaw.