Abstract

Land reform will not just reduce rural poverty, write development officials. It can raise productivity. It can promote civic engagement. Scholars routinely concur. Land reform may not always raise productivity and civic engagement, but it can - and during 1947-50 in occupied Japan it did.This account of the Japanese land reform program is a fable, a story officials and scholars tell because they wish it were true. It is not. The program did not hasten productivity growth. Instead, it probably retarded it. The areas with the most land transferred under the program did not experience the fastest rates of productivity growth. They experienced the slowest.Land reform reduced agricultural growth rates by interfering with the allocation of credit. A tenancy contract is a lease, and a lease is a capital market transaction. By precluding the use of leases, land reform effectively increased the cost of capital, reduced the amount of credit, and reduced the accuracy with which investors could target that credit. Banks provide an obvious alternative source of credit -- and post-land-reform, the areas with the fastest growth rates were those areas with the best access to those banks.The fable of land reform rests on a fictitious account of pre-war Japan. Scholars assume tenancy rates reflected poverty levels. They did not. Instead, they reflected levels of social capital. Leases were not most common in the poorest communities. Given their character as capital market transactions, they were most common in those communities where investors could turn to social networks to induce farmers to keep their word.

Highlights

  • Land reform reduced agricultural growth rates by interfering with the allocation of credit

  • Scholars of Japan: Many scholars of Japan have supported these claims about productivity

  • Economic historian Ryoichi Miwa (2012, 164-65) reasons that: Because land reform dissolved the landlord system, farmers were able to keep all of the income from the land that they owned

Read more

Summary

Scholars of Japan

Many scholars of Japan have supported these claims about productivity. Farmers who own rather than rent have stronger incentives to boost production, they explain. For instance, economic historian Ryoichi Miwa (2012, 164-65) reasons that: Because land reform dissolved the landlord system, farmers were able to keep all of the income from the land that they owned. By the late 1950s Japanese farms had grown more productive, and "land reform must be given considerable credit" (Dore, 1959, 216). After all, he mused, the program let renters avoid landlords who might have fought change. To grow rice in Japan, they will need to build a clay base, level it, add topsoil, encircle the field with waterproof dikes, and connect it to the vast network of communal irrigation sluices that traverse the village fields (Ramseyer, 1989) They will plant their seeds in one flooded field, transplant the seedlings to a bigger flooded paddy, and drain the field as the plants mature.

Land Tenure in Prewar Japan
The Land Reform
Productivity
Conclusions
Did Land Reform Promote Civic Engagement?
Findings
Correlation Coefficients
Social Capital
Full Text
Published version (Free)

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call