Abstract
The Borda Effect, first introduced by Colman and Poutney (Behav Sci 23:15–20, 1978), occurs in a preference aggregation process using the Plurality rule if given the (unique) winner there is at least one loser that is preferred to the winner by a majority of the electorate. Colman and Poutney (1978) distinguished two forms of the Borda Effect: the Weak Borda Effect, describing a situation under which the unique winner of the Plurality rule is majority dominated by only one loser; and the Strong Borda Effect, under which the Plurality winner is majority dominated by each of the losers. The Strong Borda Effect is well documented in the literature as the Strong Borda Paradox. Colman and Poutney (1978) showed that the probability of the Weak Borda Effect is not negligible; but they only focused on the Plurality rule. In this note, we extend the work of Colman and Poutney (1978) by providing, for three-candidate elections, representations of the limiting probabilities of the (Weak) Borda Effect for the whole family of scoring rules and scoring runoff rules. Our analysis leads us to highlight that there is a relation between the (Weak) Borda Effect and Condorcet efficiency. We perform our analysis under the assumptions of Impartial Culture and Impartial Anonymous Culture, which are two well-known assumptions often used for such a study.
Talk to us
Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have
Disclaimer: All third-party content on this website/platform is and will remain the property of their respective owners and is provided on "as is" basis without any warranties, express or implied. Use of third-party content does not indicate any affiliation, sponsorship with or endorsement by them. Any references to third-party content is to identify the corresponding services and shall be considered fair use under The CopyrightLaw.