Abstract

7Ihe topic of this essay, frequently discussed by initiates in private, has not so far been introduced to the main body of economic historians. My decision to assume the task of introducing it has been prompted by a personal encounter with the problem. Some time ago I showed to Dr N., a younger colleague in my field, something I had written about sales of land in the villages of the twelfth and thirteenth centuries. My argument was that the village land market and the social differences it caused were to be found in all the periods of the Middle Ages for which there is evidence.1 This conclusion aroused my colleague to a rueful comment that if I were right and he appeared to think that I was the outcome of my study, like that of other such studies, might be to create the impression that English society never changed; and where there was no change there was no history. This is, of course, a real problem. Its reality may not seem apparent to the straight historians, i.e. those who mainly occupy themselves with political narrative and biography, and least of all to the large number of antiquaries among them. But it must occur to historians whose work is 'problem-oriented'. They are mostly historians of society and culture, and they frequently share their interests with their next-door theoreticians the sociologists, the economists, the philosophers. Where they differ from the theoreticians is in their reliance on the evidence of past changes. Past change is obviously the raison d'e'tre of their being what they are: the main justification of an historical approach to problems as against other possible approaches. Many fo them might therefore share my colleague's fears, lest by playing down historical changes we remove history itself from the work of historians. Needless to say, the threat to history is not quite so wholesale. No historian

Full Text
Published version (Free)

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call