Abstract
Neoclassical economics is the stage and branch of economic science since the 1870s through the 1930s and beyond. It was mostly the product or sequel of what economists (Schumpeter 1954) call the Copernican marginalist revolution in economic theory during the 1870â90s. Specifically, the crux of marginalism was a marginalâutility theory of exchange value and its extensions (e.g., marginalâproductivity principle of income distribution) in reaction and contrast to the laborâcost conception in classical political economy. The founders or pioneers of marginalism are commonly considered to be William Jevons (England), Carl Menger (Austria), and Leon Walras (Switzerland/France), who almost simultaneously in 1871â4 âdiscoveredâ marginalâutility value theory as a putative revolutionary alternative to its laborâbased versions in Smith, Ricardo, Mill, Marx, and others. (For instance, Jevons specifically attacked Ricardo and Mill's theories, prompting neoclassical economists like Alfred Marshall to rise in their partial defense.) The term neoclassical economics was invented by (Thorstein Veblen Groenewegen 1995), a heterodox institutional economist, in the early 1900s to indicate that marginalism (e.g., marginalâutility theory) was, in virtue of utilitarianism and hedonism, essentially continuous with and so âscarcely distinguishableâ from classical political economy (which apparently overlooks the opposition of the marginalist revolution to Ricardo et al.'s labor theories of value). In this sense, the terms marginalism and neoclassical economics become interchangeable, though the first term is probably more accurate and precise for describing this stage and type of economic theory. Moreover, historians of economics such as Schumpeter (1954: 919) object that âthere is no more sense in calling the JevonsâMengerâWalras theory neoclassic than there would be in calling the Einstein theory neoâNewtonian.â This suggests that neoclassical economics is essentially marginalism (with partial exceptions like Marshall), but not conversely: the marginalist revolution is not newly, but counterâclassical (that is what makes it presumably âCopernicanâ).
Talk to us
Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have
Disclaimer: All third-party content on this website/platform is and will remain the property of their respective owners and is provided on "as is" basis without any warranties, express or implied. Use of third-party content does not indicate any affiliation, sponsorship with or endorsement by them. Any references to third-party content is to identify the corresponding services and shall be considered fair use under The CopyrightLaw.