Abstract

The modernization of EU and US antitrust regimes that has occurred in the last decade has renewed interest in the antitrust community to find an appropriate enforcement model. Indeed, the longtime struggle between harm to competitors and harm to consumer welfare has fuelled the debate on the proper legal standard to be endorsed in the enforcement of exclusionary acts. Each conduct that may lead to an anticompetitive outcome, for example, unilateral practices, collusion or mergers, has undergone a process of re-thinking of the substantive, as well as the procedural tests to be applied. This process, as regards the EU, has in particular led towards the adoption of a criterion based on efficiency considerations, and hence more focused on an economic analysis of the context in which the companies’ conducts occur. In this respect, we have experienced a ubstantial convergence between the European and the US jurisdictions, the latter being historically characterised by a more widespread use of the “rule of reason” analysis. However, despite this phenomenon of convergence, also backed by the improvement in the transatlantic cooperation between antitrust agencies, differences in the application of fundamentally similar laws have emerged. The discrepancies between the two models are still relevant in the field of exclusionary conducts. This is striking for two reasons. First, because companies are faced with the odd outcome that the same practice is allowed in one jurisdiction and prohibited in another, so they are forced to radically change their commercial policy. Second, because rebates are one of the most controversial topics in competition law: although exclusionary discounts may at times disadvantage rival firms and unduly raise their costs, any pricing behaviour by a firm that has a significant market position will inevitably disappoint competitors, but could very well benefit consumers. The differences between the EU and the US approach towards rebates were more significant before the 2003 decision in the much debated Le Page case, as we argue in this paper. While in a first phase exclusionary conducts in general and rebates in particular were in the US assessed under a consumer welfare standard, which was based on the effects of the practice on both competitors and consumers, Le Page is regarded as a step backward to a new test more focused on assumptions. The few recent cases that have followed Le Page have not yet marked a clear position, as some have distanced themselves from the standard embraced by the Le Page court. Others, in contrast, have fully applied the Le Page test. The case-law and the decisional practice at EU level has endorsed a more formalistic standard that overlooks the economic analysis of the context in which the conduct takes place, namely, the effects of the practice. As a result, exclusionary conduct decisions by the Commission and EU courts have been sometimes heavily criticized for sheltering inefficient competitors and for chilling the very essence of the competitive process. Nevertheless, the recent Discussion Paper on the application of Article 82 to exclusionary abuses has marked a move towards an effect-based approach. This effort is to be welcomed as it attempts to provide clearer rules on the distinction between lawful and exclusionary conducts. However, the way in which the effect-based test is construed, in particular the way in which the Commission reckons the share of contestable sales that should be left open to competition, casts some doubts on the appropriateness of the model suggested. These doubts are reinforced by the outcome of the first decision adopted after the issuance of the Discussion Paper (Tomra), in which the Commission applied the new test. The long-awaited judgement in the Microsoft is also analysed. In this paper, we first summarise the main business justifications which have been highlighted by the economic and business literature underlying the adoption of quantitative, or so-called “linear pricing”, and non-quantitative rebates, the so-called “non-linear pricing” or “all-units/rollback rebates”. We come to the conclusion that even non-linear pricing has specific and well-rooted economic and business motives. We then review the US and EU case-law on discounts and we discuss the enforcement standards that have been endorsed on both sides of the Atlantic in the different phases that have characterised the relevant case-law. We place greater emphasis on the most recent developments, such as Le Page and its subsequent case-law, the Discussion Paper, as well as the recent Tomra decision (and the Microsoft judgment). We outline the differences in the approach before and after Le Page and before and after the Discussion Paper. Finally, we focus on the competitors’ harm test comparing the advantages and the disadvantages of the models that have been endorsed in the EU and the US. * * * * * Selected Bibliography D.A. Crane, Multiproduct Discounting: a myth of non-price predation, Benjamin N. Cardozo School of Law, Working Paper No. 113, 2005, p. 34. F. H. Easterbrook, Predatory Strategies and Counterstrategies, University of Chicago Law Review, 1981, p. 263. E. Elhauge, Why Above-Cost Price Cuts to Drive Out Entrants Are Not Predatory – and the Implications for Defining Costs and Market Power, Yale Law Journal, 2003, p. 681. G. Federico, When are rebates exclusionary?, European Competition Law Review, [2005], p. 479. E. M. Fox, Can We Solve the Antitrust Problems of Globalization by Extra Territoriality and Cooperation? Sufficiency and Legitimacy, The Antitrust Bulletin, 2003, p. 355. A. I. Gavil, Exclusionary Distribution Strategies by Dominant Firms: Striking a Better Balance, Antitrust Law Journal, 2004, p. 3. P. Greenlee and D. Reitman, Distinguishing Competitive and Exclusionary Uses of Loyalty Discounts, The Antitrust Bulletin, 2005, p. 445. P. Greenlee and D. Reitman, An Antitrust Analysis of Bundled Loyalty Discounts, Economic Analysis Group Discussion Paper [EAG 04-13], October 2004. Greenlee and D. Reitman, Competing with Loyalty Discounts, Paper, January 2006. L. Gyselen, Rebates: Competition on the Merits or Exclusionary Practice, 8th EU Competition Law and Policy Workshop, European University Institute, June 2003. A. Heimler, Pricing below cost and loyalty discount: are they restrictive and if so when?, Competition Policy International, Volume 1, Number 2, Autumn 2005, p. 149. H. J. Hovenkamp, The Law of Exclusionary Pricing, January 2006, U Iowa Legal Studies Research Paper No. 05-34. J. Kallaugher and B. Sher, “Rebates Revisited: Anticompetitive Effects and Exclusionary Abuse Under Article 82”, European Competition Law Review, 2004, p. 263. H. Kaman and E. Bergmann, The Granting of Rebates by Market Dominant Undertakings Under Article 82 of the EC Treaty, European Competition Law Review, 2005, p. 83. B. H. Kobayashi, The economics of loyalty discount and antitrust law in the United States, Competition Policy International, Volume 1, Number 2, Autumn 2005, p. 115. S. Kolay, G. Shaffer, J.A. Ordover, All-Units Discounts in Retail Contracts, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 2004, p. 429. Peter F. Kunzlik, Globalization and Hybridization in Antitrust Enforcement: European “Borrowings” From the U.S. Approach , The Antitrust Bulletin, 2003, p. 319. W. M. Landes, R. A. Posner, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, Harvard Law Review, 1981, p. 937. O. Loewenthal, The Defence of “Objective Justification” in Application of Article 82 EC, World Competition 2005, p. 455. F. P. Maier-Rigaud, Switching Costs in Retroactive Rebates – What’s Time Got To Do with It?, Working Paper, 2005. Maier-Rigaud, Vaigauskaite, Prokent/Tomra, a textbook case?, Competition Newsletter, 2006 No. 2, pp19–24. B. Nalebuff, Exclusionary Bundling, Yale University, 2004. G. Niels and H. Jenkins, Reform of Article 82: Where the Link Between Dominance and Effects Breaks Down, European Competition Law Review, 2005, p. 605. D. L. Rubinfeld, 3M’s Bundled Rebates: An Economic Perspective, The University of Chicago Law Review, 2005, p. 243. L. J. Raskind, Comment: Convergence and Harmonization of Antitrust Principles from the Bottom – Moving from Patchwork Toward Network , The Antitrust Bulletin, 2003, p. 439. S. C. Salop, Exclusionary Conduct, Effect on Consumers, and the Flawed Profit-Sacrifice Standard, Antitrust Law Journal, 2006, p. 311. B. Sher, The Last of the Steam-powered Trains: Modernising Art. 82 EC, European Competition Law Review, 2004, p. 242. D. Spector, Loyalty rebates: an assessment of competition concerns and a proposed rule of reason, Competition Policy International, Volume 1, Number 2, Autumn 2005, p. 90. E. Thomas Sullivan, Antitrust Remedies in the U.S. and EU: Advancing a Standard of Proportionality , The Antitrust Bulletin, 2003, p. 377. W. K. Tom, D. A. Balto, N. W. Averitt, Anticompetitive Aspects of Market-share Discounts and Other Incentives to Exclusive Dealing, Antitrust Law Journal, 2000, p. 615. J. Vickers, Abuse of Market Power, The Economic Journal, 2000, p. 115. M. Furse, “Abusive Dynamics”, European Competition Law Review, 199. C. von Weizsacker, Abuse of a Dominant Position and Economics Efficiency, Journal of Competition Law, 2003, p. 59. D. Waelbroeck, Michelin II: a per se rule against rebates by dominant companies?, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 2005, p. 149. J. Warren, Le Page’s v. 3M : an Antitrust Analysis of Loyalty Rebates, New York University Law Review, 2004, p. 1605.

Full Text
Published version (Free)

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call