Abstract

Subcontracting has become a prominent business practice across many industries. Subcontracting of industrial production is generally based on short-term need for additional processing capacity, and is oftentimes employed by manufacturers to process customer orders more quickly than using only in-house production. In this article we study a popular business model where multiple manufacturers, each capable of processing his entire workload in-house, have the option to subcontract some of their operations to a single third-party with a flexible resource. Each manufacturer can deliver customer orders only after his entire batch of jobs, processed in-house and at the third-party, is completed. The third-party facility is available to several manufacturers who compete for its use. Current business practice of First-Come-First-Served (FCFS) processing of the subcontracted workloads as well as the competitive Nash equilibrium schedules developed in earlier studies result in two types of inefficiencies; the third-party capacity is not maximally utilized, and the manufacturers incur decentralization cost. In this article we develop models to assess the value created by coordinating the manufacturers' subcontracting decisions by comparing two types of centralized control against FCFS and Nash equilibrium schedules. We present optimal and/or approximate algorithms to quantify the third-party under-utilization and the manufacturers' decentralization cost. We find that both inefficiencies are more severe with competition than they are when the third-party allocates capacity in a FCFS manner. However, without centralized control, a larger percentage of the players prefer Nash equilibrium schedules to FCFS schedules. We extend our analysis to incomplete information scenarios where manufacturers reveal limited demand information, and find that more information dramatically benefits the third-party and the manufacturers, however, the marginal benefits are decreasing.Finally, we discuss an extension wherein each manufacturer's objective takes into account asymmetries in subcontracting, in-house processing, and delay costs. Finally, we discuss an extension wherein each manufacturer’s objective takes into account asymmetries in subcontracting, in-house processing, and delay costs.

Full Text
Published version (Free)

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call