Abstract

Previous articleNext article FreeCommentPaul BeaudryPaul BeaudryUniversity of British Columbia and NBER Search for more articles by this author PDFPDF PLUSFull Text Add to favoritesDownload CitationTrack CitationsPermissionsReprints Share onFacebookTwitterLinked InRedditEmailQR Code SectionsMoreI. IntroductionInspired by ideas presented in Pigou’s 1927 book on Industrial Fluctuations, Pigou cycles refer to economic fluctuations that are driven by changes in firms’ belief about the future profitability of current investment decisions. A recent literature has emerged exploring whether Pigou’s ideas may offer a reasonable explanation to business cycle episodes (revival inspired in part by the episode of the tech boom-bust of the 1990s). This literature has many challenges: theoretical, conceptual, and empirical. For example, what is the source of the change in beliefs, what are the transmission mechanisms, and are such forces empirically relevant?One of the immediate and less obvious challenges of this literature is to identify environments in which such changes in beliefs can actually cause business cycles, that is, positive comovement between investment, consumption, and employment. Although such a possibility sounds very intuitive, it is nontrivial to build fully specified (and reasonable) dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models in which changes in fundamentals that affect the future profitability of current investment actually generate business cycle phenomena. In a recent paper, Den Haan and Kaltenbrunner (2009) have shown that news about future productivity growth can generate business cycle phenomena in an environment in which jobs are subject to matching frictions. However, their results are somewhat fragile since they depended on, among others things, assuming a high degree of intertemporal elasticity of substitution in consumption. In the current paper, Den Haan and Lozej examine whether extending the analysis of the earlier paper to an international setting allows Pigou cycles to emerge for more reasonable parameter values. The main result of the paper is to show that an international setting helps a search and matching framework generate Pigou cycles for reasonable values of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in consumption. However, Den Haan and Lozej also find that for Pigou cycles to arise in an international context, it is important for trade flows to affect relative prices of imported/exported goods.In these comments, I will begin by reviewing why it is difficult to produce Pigou cycles in a simple general equilibrium environment. I will then discuss why matching frictions helps generate Pigou cycles and how the introduction of open-economy elements affects the result. Finally, I will provide a general assessment of the success and remaining challenges of this line of research.II. Expectation-Driven Fluctuation in a Two-Period EnvironmentConsider a two-period version of a standard one-sector macro model in which output is given byThe representative agent has per-period preferences given byThe driving force is taken to be news regarding θ2, with θ1 and K1 given. The question is, how does this economy respond to news about θ2 when the news is known to individuals at time 1? The equilibrium conditions for this two-period economy areWhen agents get positive news about θ2, this increases demand for current consumption, increases the demand for investment, lowers labor supply, and leaves labor demand unchanged. Hence to equilibrate, market prices will need to adjust. In the new equilibrium, it is easy to verify that R will be higher and consumption and wages in period 2 will be higher. But instead of creating a boom in period 1, the news causes a recession with lower employment, output, and investment. The one quantity that increases is consumption. This result can be partially reversed if preferences are instead given bywith σ < 1.In this case, if σ is sufficiently small, then news can give rise to an expansion in output, but now consumption will reduce. The problem with this case is that it again does not look like a business cycle. This simple example illustrates the difficulty in producing Pigou cycles in a standard equilibrium environment.Before I discuss the effects of introducting search frictions, it is useful to review both why simply placing the above setup in an open-economy environment will not solve the problem and why introducing nominal frictions is not a clear solution either. Under the assumption of a small open economy, good news about future productivity will now lead to an increase in both consumption and investment, but it will create an even greater domestic recession since employment and production will decrease more significantly in response to the consumption effects on labor supply. Introducing nominal frictions can help to generate Pigou cycles, but this has drawbacks also. In particular, results will depend on the nature of monetary policy. If monetary policy is set optimally, then the economy generally behaves as a flexible price economy, and therefore the problems associated with producing Pigou cycles illustrated above remain.III. Adding Matching FrictionsHow does adding matching frictions help? Matching frictions help on two dimensions: they affect labor demand and they affect the wage determination process. First, consider the effect on labor demand. Matching frictions act like an adjustment cost to labor. Hence, if the arrival of news causes a boom in employment next period, then this creates a need to hire more workers today since workers cannot be immediately hired at zero cost tomorrow. Given that more employment today means more output, this allows both consumption and investment to increase in response to the news. Second, the matching friction breaks the close link between the wage and marginal value of leisure. For example, the real wage can be thought as being quasi-fixed in such a case as long as it is in the bargaining set. Den Haan and Lozej do not go as far as assuming a fixed wage, but they do exploit this weaker link, thereby causing wages to respond little to wealth effects of labor supply. Accordingly, with matching frictions, news of a future boom leads to increased employment today at quasi-fixed wages.So what is the problem with this case? If σ is sufficient low, we get business cycle properties. However, if σ is set at an empirically reasonable value, we get a fall in investment as consumption absorbs all the extra output and interest rates remain high. In this case we are getting consumption and employment to move together, which is generally a difficult comovement to get; however, the model is not causing business cycle–type fluctuations since investment is not increasing.Now we can see how adding an international dimension helps. The matching friction is getting employment and output to increase, whereas a pinned-down interest rate allows both consumption and investment to increase. This all looks goods for generating Pigou cycles. However, as recognized by Den Haan and Lozej, a new problem arises in such a setting: the trade balance becomes extremely volatile. Hence, Den Haan and Lozej address this problem by adding trading frictions to better match the observed volatility of the trade balance. They consider two cases: interest rates that respond to the trade balance and import/export prices that react to import/export volumes. In the first case, they find that the economy mimics very closely the closed-economy case. In the second case, they find that the endogenous response of the price of investment exports and consumption imports greatly helps the model generate Pigou cycles. For example, the increase in the cost of imported consumption in response to news reduces the response of aggregate consumption and thereby favors even more production. The less obvious force is with respect to the price of investment goods. If the price of imported investment goods did not change, the country experiencing a positive news shock would not want to invest during the anticipation phase, knowing it can wait for the realization of the news. Hence, it would export investment goods instead of using them domestically to build up the capital stock. But when this price falls as the country tries to export (because of the friction), this creates incentives to invest domestically, and this favors the emergence of Pigou cycles in the sense of having consumption, investment, and output respond positively to news.IV. Remaining ChallengesThis leads me to the question: Does this paper provide a credible mechanism for Pigou cycles, or at least is it on the right track? To answer this question one needs to keep in mind that Pigou cycles are quite difficult to generate in a reasonable equilibrium setting. Most current proposals involve questionable departures from the baseline macro model. So in comparison to the literature, this paper nicely highlights some attractive features of how matching frictions help generate Pigou cycles. These frictions generate an expansion through a shift in labor demand—due to an adjustment cost–type mechanism—along a rather unchanging wage (in the bargaining set). That is intuitive. Such a mechanism seems at least as plausible for explaining Pigou cycles as those found in the literature, and moreover, it is shown to be quantitatively quite strong.The mechanism is nevertheless still somewhat weak on other dimensions. In particular, the theoretical impulse responses reported in the paper show that most of the movement in output comes about when actual productivity is increased, not when the news arises. Why am I worried about this? For this we need to look at evidence on news shocks. Although the evidence related to “news-driven” business cycles is controversial, my work with Franck Portier (2006) and more recent work with Bernd Lucke (2010) give some indication regarding what a model of Pigou cycles needs to explain. In this work, we have been trying to identify fluctuations induced by news shocks using structured vector autoregression methodology. Our findings, using different identification schemes, suggest that news of future growth in total factor productivity (TFP) is preceded by a period of approximately 2 years in which the economy is expanding without any increase in TFP. Most of the expansion period arises well before the increase in TFP. When TFP finally starts increasing, this is not associated with a further boom. Throughout this process, consumption, investment, and hours worked are high. These patterns are quite hard to match, and I believe that the current model does not fit them very well. In this sense, I think further modeling work is needed to explain business cycles as a response to news. Nonetheless, I view the model of Den Haan and Lozej as potentially being the right path.ReferencesBeaudry, Paul, and Bernd Lucke. 2010. “Letting Different Views about Business Cycles Compete.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2009:413–56.First citation in articleGoogle ScholarBeaudry, Paul, and Franck Portier. 2006. “News, Stock Prices and Economic Fluctuations.” American Economic Review 96, no. 4:1293–1307.First citation in articleGoogle ScholarDen Haan, W. J., and G. Kaltenbrunner. 2009. “Anticipated Growth and Business Cycles in Matching Models.” Journal of Monetary Economics 56:309–27.First citation in articleGoogle ScholarPigou, A. C. 1927. Industrial Fluctuations. London: Macmillan.First citation in articleGoogle Scholar Previous articleNext article DetailsFiguresReferencesCited by Volume 7, Number 12011 Article DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1086/658318 Views: 86 © 2011 by the National Bureau of Economic Research. All rights reserved.PDF download Crossref reports no articles citing this article.

Full Text
Published version (Free)

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call