Abstract
AbstractBioeconomic approaches to resource management treat renewable resources as naturally reproducing assets, or natural capital, whose conservation generates an economic rate of return. Stochasticity in resource growth produces stochasticity in these returns, affecting both the economic efficiency and ecological sustainability of resource use. Traditional bioeconomic models find that the rate of return to conservation is increased by a risk premium that may lower conservation incentives for more random populations. But these prescriptions depend on how the stochasticity of resource growth is modeled. Whereas the ecological literature adopts stochastic processes based on ecological considerations, bioeconomic analyses generally rely on ad hoc specifications chosen for convenience. Using analytical and numerical applications to the efficient management of fisheries and forests, we find that risk premium calculations based on traditional bioeconomic approaches versus ecological approaches may differ both quantitatively and qualitatively so that not all sources of ecological stochasticity imply conservation is risky.Recommendations for Resource ManagersBioeconomic approaches to resource management link economic and ecological models to evaluate economic–ecological tradeoffs arising from different management choices. The bioeconomic literature has focused very little on the implications of stochastic resource growth, and the specification of stochasticity in these analyses is generally ad hoc and not ecologically justifiable. We bridge this gap by adopting specifications promoted by ecologists and demonstrate as follows: Not all sources of ecological stochasticity imply conservation is risky. This result contrasts with traditional bioeconomic findings, driven by ad hoc modeling assumptions, that natural capital is always a risky investment. Whether a particular source of stochasticity implies conservation is risky may be state dependent. Even when models based on ecological notions of stochasticity do imply that conservation is risky, the magnitude of these risks and the ability of conservation efforts to manage risks may differ greatly from traditional bioeconomic specifications.
Talk to us
Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have
Disclaimer: All third-party content on this website/platform is and will remain the property of their respective owners and is provided on "as is" basis without any warranties, express or implied. Use of third-party content does not indicate any affiliation, sponsorship with or endorsement by them. Any references to third-party content is to identify the corresponding services and shall be considered fair use under The CopyrightLaw.