Abstract

After the 2008-09 financial crisis, policymakers around the world focused on enacting improvements that would make the emergence of a financial crisis less likely (ex ante) and recovery from one more rapid (ex post). This Article identifies a gap in both the academic literature and the current financial regulatory framework in exploring how to limit the damage—to other firms, and to the financial system—when a crisis is ongoing. Policymakers cannot predict the origins of every future crisis, just as firefighters cannot predict the origins of every future fire. Once one begins, how can they keep the damage from spreading?
 The academic theory on financial crisis “firefighting” divides into two main camps. The “capital view” claims that runs on financial institutions are fundamentally rational, and that investors care mainly about solvency. Under this view, the best way to fight runs is to raise capital requirements ahead of time, to multiples of current levels. The “contagion view” claims instead that the lack of liquid assets both defines and causes bank runs; an institution’s access to cash (and instruments like it) determines whether and when investors will withdraw funding. Under this view, the best way to fight runs is for governments to lend banks money—freely, at high rates, and against good collateral—and to promise to do so well before a crisis starts.
 In this Article—the first to directly address this question empirically—we show that neither view fits the most catastrophic financial shock of the last ninety years: the 2008 Lehman Brothers bankruptcy. In some cases, banks with more capital and liquidity were actually more exposed, not less, to the market panic following Lehman’s collapse. By contrast, we show that simple market correlation was a powerful predictor of exposure to the Lehman run. We also show that market valuations of large banks are more highly correlated today than they were in September 2008, creating a potential unaddressed conduit for an unexpected shock to metastasize into a contagious run.

Highlights

  • A decade removed from the peak of the 2008-09 financial crisis and after hundreds of published articles, academics and policymakers are still working to understand systemic risk in the financial sector

  • [Vol 2020 was not until 30 years after the Great Depression that Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz published A Monetary History of the United States in 1963, with its canonical critique of Federal Reserve Board policy in the 1930s . . . . [O]n the time scale needed to fully absorb the significance of major financial disasters, we are in the early days and should not expect to reach immediate consensus on either diagnoses or prognoses.”[1]. What all practitioners and scholars agree is that a crisis begins with an unexpected shock

  • We are aware of only one study that examines how capital and liquidity levels affected the responses of investors in financial institutions to the Lehman failure.[90]

Read more

Summary

Introduction

A decade removed from the peak of the 2008-09 financial crisis and after hundreds of published articles, academics and policymakers are still working to understand systemic risk in the financial sector. This long progression is as expected; “it [Vol 2020 was not until 30 years after the Great Depression that Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz published A Monetary History of the United States in 1963, with its canonical critique of Federal Reserve Board policy in the 1930s . The day’s trading began with news that Lehman had gone under, and that the accounts of Lehman’s British and Japanese brokerage operations had been frozen.[4]

Results
Discussion
Conclusion
Full Text
Published version (Free)

Talk to us

Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have

Schedule a call