Abstract
BackgroundDespite evidence of nonproportional trade-offs in time trade-off exercises and the explicit incorporation of exponential discounting in health technology assessment calculations, quality-adjusted life-year (QALY) tariffs are currently still established under the assumption of linear time preferences. ObjectivesThe aim of this study was to introduce a general method of accommodating for nonlinear time preferences in discrete choice experiment (DCE) duration studies and to evaluate its impact on estimated QALY tariffs. MethodsA parsimonious utility function is proposed that accommodates any discounting function and preserves linear time preferences as a special case. Based on an efficient DCE design and 1775 respondents from a nationally representative scientific household panel, preferences and QALY tariffs for the Dutch SF-6D were estimated while accommodating for nonlinear time preferences via exponential and hyperbolic discounting functions. ResultsWhen the discount rate was estimated directly, we found strong evidence of nonlinear time preferences (with an exponential and hyperbolic discount rate of 5.7% and 16.5%, respectively). When the discount rate was estimated as a function of health state severity, we found that years lived in better health states are discounted minus years lived in impaired health states. Finally, the best statistical fit was obtained when using a hyperbolic discount function, which resulted in smaller QALY decrements and fewer health states classified as worse than immediate death. ConclusionsOur results highlight the relevance and even necessity of a paradigm shift in health valuation studies in favor of time-preference corrected QALY tariffs, with potentially important implications for health technology assessment calculations and regulatory decisions.
Highlights
Economic evaluations in health care are often based on qualityadjusted life-years (QALYs), providing an intuitive and straightforward approach to combine quality and duration of life into a single index [1,2]
discrete choice experiment (DCE) have a solid theoretical foundation [9,10,11], require less abstract reasoning, more closely resemble real-life decisions, and can typically be administered online
An important issue regarding the use of DCEs in health state valuations is that DCEs only provide information about the relative value of health states, ranging from the best to the worst included health state, and on a latent utility scale that is different in each estimation
Summary
Economic evaluations in health care are often based on qualityadjusted life-years (QALYs), providing an intuitive and straightforward approach to combine quality and duration of life into a single index [1,2]. The required preference weights for QALY calculations were derived using time trade-off (TTO) and standard gamble techniques These valuation techniques required respondents to iterate toward a point of indifference between two health outcomes. Despite evidence of nonproportional trade-offs in time trade-off exercises and the explicit incorporation of exponential discounting in health technology assessment calculations, qualityadjusted life-year (QALY) tariffs are currently still established under the assumption of linear time preferences. Objectives: The aim of this study was to introduce a general method of accommodating for nonlinear time preferences in discrete choice experiment (DCE) duration studies and to evaluate its impact on estimated QALY tariffs. Based on an efficient DCE design and 1775 respondents from a nationally representative scientific household panel, preferences and QALY tariffs for the Dutch SF-6D were estimated while accommodating for nonlinear time preferences via exponential and hyperbolic discounting functions.
Talk to us
Join us for a 30 min session where you can share your feedback and ask us any queries you have
Disclaimer: All third-party content on this website/platform is and will remain the property of their respective owners and is provided on "as is" basis without any warranties, express or implied. Use of third-party content does not indicate any affiliation, sponsorship with or endorsement by them. Any references to third-party content is to identify the corresponding services and shall be considered fair use under The CopyrightLaw.