M ODERN investment functions, springing from the work of Jorgenson,' differ from earlier investment functions in that they start with an explicit assumption about the economy's aggregate production function. In particular, Jorgenson assumes a Cobb-Douglas production function. Starting with an explicit production function means that it is possible to calculate algebraically the impact of factors, such as interest rates, that could not be isolated in earlier investment functions. Choosing the correct production function is important in estimating partial effects, but the proper definition of the cost of capital variable is also central to their correct estimation. Formulations other than those of Jorgenson are possible. If one had priors about the differences in the opportunity cost of capital under the Duesenberry supply of funds hypothesis,2 the cost of capital could be defined to embody these priors. Doing so would lead to different estimates of the partial effects of tax rates, interest rates, and depreciation policies. Thus, the partial effects that emerge from a modern investment function are a product of the initial specifications of the production function and the cost of capital variable. In addition to choosing the correct production function and the correct definition of the cost of capital, there are other directions in which the modern investment function can be modified. In Jorgenson's neoclassical equilibrium world the cost of capital and the marginal product of capital are always identical. Thus, the desired capital stock at any moment of time is equal to output divided by the marginal product of capital (the cost of capital) multiplied by the elasticity of output with respect to capital. Thus, the only problems are ones of correct data measurement and estimation of the lag structure. This formulation has some theoretical problems. Introducing lags means that the economy is not in equilibrium. actual capital stock lags behind the desired capital stock. Therefore, the cost of capital and the marginal product of capital are not equal. Even if they were equal, the marginal product of capital will differ before and after expansion of the capital stock. Thus output should be divided by the expected cost of capital rather than the actual cost of capital to determine the desired capital stock.3 In a disequilibrium world, the cost of capital and the marginal product of capital can diverge. Profit maximizing firms invest to eliminate the gap between the marginal product of capital and the cost of capital. investment necessary to eliminate this gap depends upon the economy's production function. This paper investigates a disequilibrium investment function based on a Cobb-Douglas production function and Jorgenson's definition of the cost of capital. I was led to investigate such a model in the process of attempting to use the Jorgenson investment function.4 Several problems emerged in addition to those investigated elsewhere.5 (1) Although the Jorgenson investment function fit quarterly time series data for producers' * author would like to thank the referee for many useful comments. 'Dale W. Jorgenson, Anticipations and Behavior, in J. S. Duesenberry, E. Kuh, G. Fromm, and L. R. Klein (editors), Brookings Quarterly Econometric Model of the United States (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1965). Rational Distributed Lag Functions, Econometrica, XXXIV (Jan. 1966), 135-149. With Calvin D. Siebert, A Comparison of Alternative Theories of Corporate Behavior, American Economic Review, XVIII (Sept. 1968). Optimal Capital Accumulation and Corporate Behavior, Journal of Political Economy, LXXVI (Nov./Dec. 1968), 1123-1151. With J. A. Stephenson, The Time Structure of Behavior in United States Manufacturing, 1947-60, this REvIEw, XLIV (Feb. 1967), 16-27. Investment Behavior in U.S. Manufacturing, 1947-60, Econometrica, XXXV (April 1967), 169-220. 2J. Duesenberry, Business Cycles and Economic Growth (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1968), 87-112. 3This was pointed out to me by my colleague Duncan Foley. 'Anyone wishing the detailed econometric results of my attempts to fit the Jorgenson model to producer's durable equipment and nonresidential structures can have them by writing to me. 'Robert Eisner and M. I. Nadiri, Investment Behavior and Neoclassical Theory, this REvIEw, L (Aug. 1968).
Read full abstract